22 November 2010
The Best U.S. Business Schools 2010
Working through the post-crash hangover, B-schools put new emphasis on job placement—and some hard lessons learned
By Geoff Gloeckler
Jack Oakes didn't like what he was seeing. As director of the Career Development Center at the University of Virginia's Darden School of Business, Oakes had watched the Great Recession choke off his students' job opportunities. The outlook was no better for the MBA Class of 2010. By the end of February only 64 percent of students reported having received a job offer, even worse than the recession-era low of 69 percent in February 2009 (and well below the 81 percent in pre-crash 2008). In the world of elite MBA programs such as Darden, where graduates have come to expect multiple six-figure offers, this qualified as a disaster. Something had to be done.
On Mar. 16, Oakes asked three of the school's best-known and longest-tenured professors to send an e-mail to alumni explaining the crisis and asking for help. The subject line: "A Darden Call to Arms." "It might not have been war, but for many of these students who were still looking for jobs, it sure felt like it," Oakes says.
Within hours, dozens of Darden alumni responded with job leads. By graduation in May, 77 percent of the class had job offers; three months later the figure reached 87 percent. "It was something we had never done in the past," Oakes says. "We didn't have to. But things are different now."
Because the financial crisis killed or downsized some of the biggest MBA employers, including Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers, the B-school job search has grown far more arduous. That's clear from Bloomberg Businessweek's 2010 ranking of the top full-time MBA programs. Consider this contrast: Three months after graduation in 2007, only 4 percent of grads at the 30 top U.S. schools did not have a job offer. That figure has risen to 12 percent, and at some schools it's more than double that. Even top schools lost ground. At No. 1 University of Chicago Booth School of Business, 9 percent of students were jobless at the three-month mark, vs. 2.4 percent in 2007, while No. 3 University of Pennsylvania Wharton School saw its three-month unemployment rate more than triple, from 3.9 percent to 13 percent, over the same period.
No longer can students rely on the traditional on-campus recruiting process. More than 40 percent of B-school career services officers saw a decline in on-campus visits this spring, according to the MBA Career Services Council (CSC). And when companies do come to campus, instead of having a dozen positions to fill, they might have two or three. Starting salaries among all MBAs surveyed by Bloomberg Businessweek have dropped nearly 6 percent, from an average of $104,500 in 2008 to $98,400 this year. And students' plans are changing, with many settling for lesser positions. More than half of those surveyed expressed concern about the job market. "I had to expand my job search to include potential jobs and industries I would otherwise have never considered," says Tyler Fenelon, a 2010 graduate of UCLA's Anderson School of Management (No. 17). He was able to find the private equity job he'd hoped for. "I consider myself very lucky," he says.
Schools are finding new ways for students to connect with companies that might not recruit on campus. At top-ranked Booth, the employer outreach team has tripled in size, from two to six, in the past two years. Last summer the team met with more than 350 companies, up from 100 in 2007. "We definitely have more corporate relationships now than we did a few years ago," says Julie Morton, associate dean of career services. "We used to assume the relationship began when a company recruited on campus. Now a strong relationship is one where a firm thinks of Booth in terms of sourcing talent--posting a job, coming to campus, or simply interacting with students."
Schools are also teaming up to bring students to recruiters. In April, 128 students from seven schools—including Michigan's Ross School of Business (No. 7), Cornell's Johnson Graduate School of Management (No. 13), and Notre Dame's Mendoza College of Business (No. 24)—traveled to San Francisco for "A Day in the Bay MBA Interview Forum." The event allowed 36 Bay Area employers, including eBay, Electronic Arts, and the San Francisco Fed, to meet top MBA talent without having to incur the expense of traveling to each campus.
Technology also makes it easier for students to connect with recruiters. At Northwestern University's Kellogg School of Management (No. 4), Skype has become a familiar tool for job seekers, and when Stanford's Graduate School of Business (No. 5) begins its transition into its new Knight Management Center next spring, two Cisco TelePresence videoconference facilities will be available for remote interviews. Videoconferencing "gives students an opportunity that they might not otherwise have," says Cynthia Bush, director of recruiting at Houlihan Lokey, the Los Angeles investment bank. The technology is especially valuable to companies that might hire only a handful of MBAs each year, says Gideon Gradman, vice-president for corporate development at Boston-based Ze-gen, a venture-backed energy startup. "It's not a perfect replacement for in-person interviews, but it's an enabling technology for companies like ours that are small and don't want to be limited geographically."
Before the job market soured, regional companies would not have been on the radar for many top MBAs, but now career services advisers are recommending that students not limit their job search to a single function, industry, or location. Those who have their hearts set on a "go-to" MBA position in finance should think twice. In late September, Bank of America began laying off employees in its investment banking unit; just a few days later Morgan Stanley announced a hiring freeze in its i-bank group for the rest of 2010. "In the past, students have focused their internship and job search with one specific, singular path," says Nicole Hall, president of the MBA CSC and executive director of career services at Pepperdine University's Graziadio School of Business and Management. "Now students have to have a flexible outlook with two or three viable options that they pursue aggressively."
For some students, the best option is to change course entirely. After watching MBAs from the Class of 2009 at Brigham Young's Marriott School of Management (No. 27) struggle to find work, Anthony Strike decided to forgo his second year at the school. Instead of accumulating another year of debt, he dove into a full-time job search. After three months he landed a job as product manager at Apria Healthcare in Orange County, Calif. "It was the nontraditional choice," Strike says, "but it was the right choice for me."
Students are also being called on to provide assistance to job-seeking classmates. At Chicago, 39 second-year MBAs are serving as career advisers, meeting one-on-one with first-years to share their experiences in the internship and job search. Last spring student leaders at Indiana's Kelley School of Business (No. 19) created a group informally called the Jobless Lonely Hearts Club. Each week leading up to graduation, about 30 job seekers from the Kelley Class of 2010 met to share leads and commiserate over pizza and beer. Classmates who had already secured employment served as facilitators. "At first it was awkward," says Darshan Shah, one of the facilitators, "but after those first couple of sessions, we started seeing results. It really brought our class closer together." Shah says at least five participants ultimately found jobs using contacts picked up from the club.
Happily, there are signs that the job market for MBAs is picking up. More than half of the top programs reported that a higher percentage of students from the Class of 2011 had returned to campus from their summer internships with firm offers. Sectors such as health care and energy are also increasing their full-time job recruiting activity, according to the MBA CSC. Peter Giulioni, assistant dean of career services at the University of Southern California Marshall School of Business (No. 26), expects the recruiting landscape to return to a more traditional model of primarily on-campus recruiting within 18 to 24 months. Good news for the Class of 2012, perhaps, but cold comfort for this year's graduates.
Gloeckler is a staff editor for Bloomberg Businessweek in New York.
19 November 2010
ADB approves $135m loan for IGCC power plant in China
The $419.59m project is scheduled to be completed by 2012. The loan has a 26-year term, including a grace period of six years, with the interest rate determined in accordance with ADB's Libor-based lending facility. The loan component is due for completion by June 2012 and the grant component by June 2015.
Ashok Bhargava, principal energy specialist in ADB's east Asia department, said: "The project will demonstrate the advantages of a technology with the potential for large greenhouse gas emission reductions. Its successful implementation will bolster the confidence of investors, project developers, and policymakers leading to scaled-up IGCC power plants and their expanded deployment."
China has launched a clean coal power generation program, GreenGen, to reduce pollution as well as lower the GHG emissions, with the Tianjin project being the cornerstone of the first phase, ADB said. ADB is also providing $1.25m in technical assistance to pave the way for the second and third phases of the program, which will result in a scaled-up IGCC plant fitted with carbon capture and storage technology by 2013.
The remaining costs of the Tianjin project will be funded from equity contributions of $84m, a loan of $195.59m from a group of local banks, and the grant from ADB's climate change fund. China Huaneng Group, the managing partner of the GreenGen program, is the executing agency for the project.
www.szwgroup.com
15 November 2010
G20 Aftermath: Did We Lose The Battle And Win The War?
The narrative emerging in the wake of the G-20 meetings is that, not only is the rest of the world angry at us over quantitative easing, but we also achieved none of our diplomatic objectives regarding rebalancing (the coverage seemed particularly negative on CNBC). [1] [2] [3] In addition, the outcome has been taken as a harbinger of the end of US dominance over economic policymaking, to the extent the US no longer has the intellectual high ground (given the failure to regulate the financial system in a sensible way) and the relative decline in economic weight.
Effective Economics versus Meaningful Communiques, and Strategic Interactions
I think one important point is to realize that achieving economic goals and diplomatic successes are not always the same. From a diplomatic standpoint, it would have been useful to have agreement that countries should limit current account balances, as in the US proposal. It might have been economically useful, to the extent that this put additional pressure on China to take more rapid action to rein in their current account surplus by way of exchange rate appreciation, and restructuring of the economy. Of course, at the panel I was on several weeks ago [4], PBoC deputy governor had already made a commitment to putting the Chinese CA/GDP ratio on a glide path towards reduction (but not necessarily as a share of world GDP), so it's not clear what economic impact an agreement would have made.
I have also been thinking about the anger with which the policymakers and economists in the rest-of-the-world (as well as certain US politicians [5]) have greeted QE2 with. In some ways, the fact that they are angry speaks volumes about the effectiveness or ineffectiveness of QE2. (In other words, to criticize QE2 as having no effect, and then to be angry that it is being undertaken, are internally inconsistent views.)
My view is that anger at the US position is currently being driven by an understanding that QE2 has been surprisingly effective at depreciating the dollar, and that the rest-of-the-world has limited scope in countering that depreciation. In a game theoretic context, we usually think of competitive devaluation as a form of the prisoner’s dilemma, where the devalue option dominates the no-devalue option, and both parties end up with a devalued currency, but no net improvement because countries cannot all devalue against each other.
However, because of the radically different post-recession economic conditions facing the US and China, the payoff matrix has changed. The US gains by allowing the currency to depreciate against the rest-of-the-world, but the Chinese (and to a lesser extent the other BRICs) have competing goals of maintaining rapid growth, high exports, and stable inflation. This point has become apparent as inflation has surged in China. [6] The conflicting goals Chinese policymakers face can be illustrated by reference to the Mundell-Fleming model. (See this post for detail).
The Chinese can raise interest rates in order to stabilize inflation by cooling off the economy. However, that interest rate increase would exacerbate the capital inflow that would tend to appreciate the CNY. That in turn implies even greater forex intervention by PBoC, which in turn requires even greater sterilization measures, either by issuing more PBoC bonds, or by raising reserve requirements. The US measures to push down long term rates via QE2 have made that option more difficult.
If the Chinese are unable to rein in inflation via sterilization measures (and other administrative measures to cool off the economy), then the Chinese real exchange rate will appreciate, even if the nominal does not move. Recall the definition of the real exchange rate (in logs):
q = s - p + pUS
Where s is the log exchange rate expressed as CNY per USD, p is the log Chinese price level, and pUS is the log US price level, and q is the log real exchange rate; up is depreciation of the CNY. As p rises, q falls. This argument is merely an assertion that the monetary approach to the balance of payments holds in the long run.
The highlighting of this tradeoff by US actions might just induce the Chinese policymakers to accelerate measures to re-balance in a way external diplomatic pressure (from the US, the other G-20) did not.
Why Is the Exchange Rate Moving So Much?
As I noted earlier [6], there is some mystery why the impact on the exchange rate has been so much more marked than that on long term rates. As several observers have observed [Delong] [Krugman], QE2 is fairly small in quantitative magnitude, and in terms of implied impact on duration adjusted interest rates. Theory suggests offsetting inflation and liquidity effects from open market operations, so the impact on observed nominal rates could in principle be small (and in either direction).
I think a large chunk of the impact comes from the fact that QE2 signals additional information about the willingness of the monetary authorities to undertake actions to stimulate the economy, perhaps by future injections [7]. I will also observe that the likelihood of a sensible fiscal policy declined after the mid-term elections (that is the US will more likely undertake contractionary fiscal policy by not offsetting state spending reductions), so that from a simple Mundell-Fleming model, we should expect dollar depreciation.
What about Capital Controls?
There has been substantial discussion of whether capital controls can limit the capital inflows into emerging markets, thereby loosening the choice between exchange rate stability and monetary autonomy (i.e., "the trilemma", as discussed here and here). I believe that capital controls can be effective, particularly in the short term, in reducing and changing the composition of capital inflows. Whether capital controls can be effective over the longer term in stemming these inflows to a substantial degree remains open. (see for instance the recent IMF paper here [pdf]).
Of course, if extensive capital controls are combined with financial repression, and pervasive controls over the rest of the economy, then capital flows can be controlled, as in China. Even then, capital controls only allow reserve accumulation/decumulation to loosen the binds of the trilemma. [8]
The Bigger Game
The depreciation game between the US and the other G-20 countries is imbedded in other games. Moreover, the game is repeated (the dollar depreciation is one-shot, with repercussions into the future). Perhaps more importantly from my perspective, strategic interactions involving macro policies are imbedded in a larger game involving other policies including those related to trade. GI/Free Exchange discusses whether trade protection and depreciation are complements or substitutes. My colleague Mark Copelovitch, along with UW Professor Jon Pevehouse, has undertaken some systematic research on the subject of exchange rate regime choice and protection (presentation here), which suggests that they are substitutes.
Thinking in the context of the current game, China could retaliate, although not necessarily by using tariffs (rare metals comes to mind). We'll have to wait and see; however, to the extent that China relies more profoundly on access to US markets than the US relies on access to Chinese markets (still), I'm dubious they will follow this path with full force.
Concluding Thoughts
None of the foregoing should be taken to mean that failure to come to an agreement on a formal statement restricting current account imbalances was a good thing. Certainly it would have been preferable to have an additional lever to induce more rapid action on the Chinese yuan. But it's always important to recall what the economic fundamentals are, and right now it appears that the scope remains for the US to induce additional expenditure switching.
Hence, the US has, either intentionally or unintentionally, "pulled the trigger" (after all, it's not clear Bernanke was thinking about the dollar, as opposed to domestic economic activity); we are now using our special position as a key reserve currency to depreciate our currency at exactly the time when other key countries (the BRICs) are not fully able to counter, since their output gaps are positive, and stronger currencies would help them counter inflationary pressures [9]
One last speculation. The other countries facing a negative output gap (primarily other advanced countries) will face the same incentives as the US, and so will more likely try to depreciate their currencies. It's true that this will tend to negate the US depreciation -- but to the extent that this induces greater monetary easing in those countries, this is a positive outcome.
Some words of caution about overinterpretation from Simon Evenett. Richard Portes also assesses the macro implications of the Seoul meetings. Paletta/RTE parses the words.
This post was published at Econbrowser >
อย่าฝืนโลก
คอลัมน์ สามัญสำนึก
โดย สมปรารถนา คล้ายวิเชียนร
วันที่ 15 พฤศจิกายน พ.ศ. 2553 ปีที่ 34 ฉบับที่ 4262 ประชาชาติธุรกิจ
ได้มีโอกาสรับฟังข้อมูลจากผู้รู้ในแวดวงธุรกิจการเงินและเศรษฐกิจมหภาคที่ มอง-วิเคราะห์เชิงโครงสร้างของระบบเศรษฐกิจโลก เกี่ยวกับมาตรการอัดฉีดเศรษฐกิจระลอกล่าสุดของสหรัฐอเมริกา มหาอำนาจผู้กุมชะตากรรมเศรษฐกิจโลกเอาไว้ในมือ
ช่วยให้เกิดความเข้า ใจและเชื่อมโยงความสัมพันธ์ของ หลาย ๆ เรื่องได้ดียิ่งขึ้นพอสมควร อันเนื่องมาจากทักษะในการถ่ายทอดของผู้บรรยายที่อธิบายความและเปรียบเทียบ ให้ ผู้ฟังที่มีพื้นฐานความรู้เศรษฐกิจไม่แข็งแรงอย่างผู้เขียนมองปรากฏการณ์ได้ กระจ่างมากยิ่งขึ้น
ก่อนจะสรุปตามความเข้าใจเอาเองแบบบ้าน ๆ ว่า ทั้งหมดทั้งปวงนั้นก็เป็นเพราะเราต่างอยู่ในโลกเศรษฐกิจการค้าที่เชื่อมโยง เกาะเกี่ยวกัน โดยมีพี่ใหญ่อย่างสหรัฐ ต้นตำรับของระบบทุนนิยมเสรีเป็นผู้กำหนดทิศทาง พร้อมกับความเชื่อของคนส่วนใหญ่ที่ว่า สหรัฐและระบบเศรษฐกิจของเขา "ล้มไม่ได้" ปล่อยให้ถดถอย ดิ่งซึมต่อไปจะส่งผลกระทบต่อทั้งโลก ดังนั้นจึงเป็นเรื่องชอบธรรมแล้วที่จะเพิ่มมาตรการอัดฉีด ถมเงินเข้าไปตามแต่จะเห็นสมควร
อย่าได้แคร์ว่านี่คือกติกาแบบปลาใหญ่ กินปลาเล็ก ไม่ต้องกังวลหรอกว่ามาตรการดังกล่าวจะทำให้ค่าเงินดอลลาร์อ่อนลงอีกกี่ เปอร์เซ็นต์ ในทางตรงข้ามค่าเงินหยวน, เยน, บาท, รูปี จะแข็งขึ้นเท่าไรก็ย่อมเป็นไปตามกลไกตลาดปกติที่ฝ่ายหนึ่งอ่อน อีกฝ่ายหนึ่งก็ต้องแข็งโดยปริยายนั่นเอง
แล้วหากเงินที่เพิ่มขึ้นจะ ไหลบ่าท่วมล้นระบายมายังฟากตะวันออกที่อัตราตอบแทนในการลงทุนของประเทศที่ GDP สวยหรูในระดับ 7-9% อย่างจีน สิงคโปร์ อินเดีย ไทย ฯลฯ ก็เป็นเรื่องที่ต้องตั้งรับ บริหารจัดการกันไปตามสภาพ
นี่คือความ จริงที่อาจดูไม่ค่อยดี หรือมีความเป็นธรรมเท่าใดนัก (และแม้จะเป็นประเด็นร้อนที่ถกเถียงจิกกัดกันเต็มที่ในการประชุม G-20 ก็จะไม่ก่อให้เกิดความเปลี่ยนแปลง แต่อย่างใด) แต่ก็เป็นความจริงแท้ที่ต้องเรียนรู้และทำความเข้าใจกับโลกแห่งการแข่งขัน ของทุนนิยมบนข้อได้เปรียบของ ผู้แข็งแกร่งกว่า
รู้แจ้งประจักษ์ในเหตุแห่งปัญหาดังกล่าวแล้ว ข้อแนะนำโดยผู้รู้จึงตั้งอยู่บนหลักการพื้นฐานที่ว่า "อย่าไปฝืนโลก"
เพราะฝืนอย่างไรก็ยากที่จะเอาชนะ "ระบบ" ที่กดครอบจนแม้กระทั่ง "ยักษ์ใหม่" อย่างจีนยังฝืนต้านได้แค่ในระดับหนึ่งเท่านั้น
แทน ที่จะมัวมานั่งกังวลว่า จะเอาชนะ "ระบบ" อย่างไร จะสร้างทำนบ สร้างเขื่อนกั้นการไหลบ่าของ "ทุนต่างประเทศ" แบบไหน อาจต้องกลับมาคิดใหม่ว่า แล้วจะอยู่อย่างไรกับกระแสหรือสถานการณ์ที่ "ฝืนไม่ได้" มากกว่า
มองภาพใหญ่ดังที่ผู้รู้วาดให้ดูแล้ว ก็เตรียมใจได้ว่า ประเทศไทยต้องกลับมาเตรียมตัวให้พร้อมที่จะอยู่กับยุคสมัย "บาทแข็ง" ต่อไปอีกนานพอสมควร
ประเด็นจึงกลับมาอยู่ตรงที่ว่า จะอยู่อย่างไรมากกว่า
ปฏิเสธ ไม่ได้ว่าจะเป็นยุค "บาทอ่อน" (เหมือนเมื่อครั้งหลังปี 2540) หรือยุค "บาทแข็ง" ที่กำลังเผชิญอยู่นี้ต้องมีคนที่เจ็บปวด เสียประโยชน์ หรืออาจถึงขั้นล้มหายตายจาก
แต่ก็ไม่ใช่ทั้งหมด จำนวนหนึ่งได้อานิสงส์ อีกไม่น้อยสามารถปรับตัว ประคองตัว หรือสร้าง "วิกฤตเป็นโอกาส" ได้ด้วยเหมือนกัน
โจทย์ คือจะทำอะไรให้เกิดประโยชน์ได้บ้างจากยุคค่าบาทแข็งที่ไม่ใช่แค่มองเห็นเป็น โอกาสในการนำเข้าสินค้าฟุ่มเฟือยจากอเมริกา-ยุโรปที่ราคาถูกลง หรือเป็นจังหวะดีในการเดินทางไปเที่ยวต่างประเทศให้บ่อยขึ้น ช็อปปิ้งจากนิวยอร์กจดปารีสได้อย่างเมามันมากขึ้น
การไม่ฝืนโลกคือ ความพยายามที่จะปรับปรุง เปลี่ยนแปลงค้นหาวิธีอยู่ร่วมกับภาวะนั้น ๆ อย่างยั่งยืนให้มากที่สุด หรือแสวงหาโอกาสใหม่ ๆ ที่จะเป็นประโยชน์ได้ในระยะยาว มิใช่เพียงผลพลอยได้ในระยะเฉพาะหน้า
นั่น คือฉากหนึ่งของโลกเศรษฐกิจระบอบโลกาภิวัตน์ ที่เมื่อกระโจนเข้าร่วมกระแสไปด้วยแล้ว ก็ต้องประคองตัวให้รอดไม่ว่ากระแสจะไหลเชี่ยวขนาดไหนก็ตาม
ส่วนอีกโลกที่ชอบกล่าวอ้างถึงโลกประชาธิปไตย ซึ่งยังมีอีกไม่มากประเทศนักยังฝืนกระแสอยู่นั้น
ดูเหมือนเมืองไทยจะสามารถไหลตามและฝืนกระแสได้อย่างแนบเนียนมานานแล้ว...
China buys up the world
And the world should stay open for business
From The Economist
IN THEORY, the ownership of a business in a capitalist economy is irrelevant. In practice, it is often controversial. From Japanese firms’ wave of purchases in America in the 1980s and Vodafone’s takeover of Germany’s Mannesmann in 2000 to the more recent antics of private-equity firms, acquisitions have often prompted bouts of national angst.
Such concerns are likely to intensify over the next few years, for China’s state-owned firms are on a shopping spree. Chinese buyers—mostly opaque, often run by the Communist Party and sometimes driven by politics as well as profit—have accounted for a tenth of cross-border deals by value this year, bidding for everything from American gas and Brazilian electricity grids to a Swedish car company, Volvo.
There is, understandably, rising opposition to this trend. The notion that capitalists should allow communists to buy their companies is, some argue, taking economic liberalism to an absurd extreme. But that is just what they should do, for the spread of Chinese capital should bring benefits to its recipients, and the world as a whole.
Not so long ago, government-controlled companies were regarded as half-formed creatures destined for full privatisation. But a combination of factors—huge savings in the emerging world, oil wealth and a loss of confidence in the free-market model—has led to a resurgence of state capitalism. About a fifth of global stockmarket value now sits in such firms, more than twice the level ten years ago.
The rich world has tolerated the rise of mercantilist economies before: think of South Korea’s state-led development or Singapore’s state-controlled firms, which are active acquirers abroad. Yet China is different. It is already the world’s second-biggest economy, and in time is likely to overtake America. Its firms are giants that until now have been inward-looking but are starting to use their vast resources abroad.
Chinese firms own just 6% of global investment in international business. Historically, top dogs have had a far bigger share than that. Both Britain and America peaked with a share of about 50%, in 1914 and 1967 respectively. China’s natural rise could be turbocharged by its vast pool of savings. Today this is largely invested in rich countries’ government bonds; tomorrow it could be used to buy companies and protect China against rich countries’ devaluations and possible defaults.
Chinese firms are going global for the usual reasons: to acquire raw materials, get technical know-how and gain access to foreign markets. But they are under the guidance of a state that many countries consider a strategic competitor, not an ally. As our briefing explains (see article), it often appoints executives, directs deals and finances them through state banks. Once bought, natural-resource firms can become captive suppliers of the Middle Kingdom. Some believe China Inc can be more sinister than that: for example, America thinks that Chinese telecoms-equipment firms pose a threat to its national security.
Private companies have played a big part in delivering the benefits of globalisation. They span the planet, allocating resources as they see fit and competing to win customers. The idea that an opaque government might come to dominate global capitalism is unappealing. Resources would be allocated by officials, not the market. Politics, not profit, might drive decisions. Such concerns are being voiced with increasing fervour. Australia and Canada, once open markets for takeovers, are creating hurdles for China’s state-backed firms, particularly in natural resources, and it is easy to see other countries becoming less welcoming too.
That would be a mistake. China is miles away from posing this kind of threat: most of its firms are only just finding their feet abroad. Even in natural resources, where it has been most active in dealmaking, it is not close to controlling enough supply to rig the market for most commodities.
Nor is China’s system as monolithic as foreigners often assume. State companies compete at home and their decision-making is consensual rather than dictatorial. When abroad they may have mixed motives, and some sectors—defence and strategic infrastructure, for instance—are too sensitive to allow them in. But such areas are relatively few.
What if Chinese state-owned companies run their acquisitions for politics, not profit? So long as other firms could satisfy consumers’ needs, it would not matter. Chinese companies could safely be allowed to own energy firms, for instance, in a competitive market where customers could turn to other suppliers. And if Chinese firms throw subsidised capital around the world, that’s fine. America and Europe could use the money. The danger that cheap Chinese capital might undermine rivals can be better dealt with by beefing up competition law than by keeping investment out.
Not all Chinese companies are state-directed. Some are largely independent and mainly interested in profits. Often these firms are making the running abroad. Take Volvo’s new owner, Geely. Volvo should now be able to sell more cars in China; without the deal its future was bleak.
Chinese firms can bring new energy and capital to flagging companies around the world; but influence will not just flow one way. To succeed abroad, Chinese companies will have to adapt. That means hiring local managers, investing in local research and placating local concerns—for example by listing subsidiaries locally. Indian and Brazilian firms have an advantage abroad thanks to their private-sector DNA and more open cultures. That has not been lost on Chinese managers.
China’s advance may bring benefits beyond the narrowly commercial. As it invests in the global economy, so its interests will become increasingly aligned with the rest of the world’s; and as that happens its enthusiasm for international co-operation may grow. To reject China’s advances would thus be a disservice to future generations, as well as a deeply pessimistic statement about capitalism’s confidence in itself.
Being eaten by the dragon
From The Economist
A FEW years ago two executives of an international oil company were working late in its otherwise deserted office in England. A stunning young Chinese woman arrived at reception. “She was very attractive, decked out in Gucci,” one of them says. She delivered a letter from Sinopec, one of China’s giant, state-controlled energy firms, proposing a multibillion-dollar takeover. The executive adds, a little wistfully, that she then disappeared into the night in a car with local licence plates, never to be seen again.
His firm was soon bought by another Chinese company. Since then Western bosses have been tapped by Chinese firms at conferences in Toronto and Cape Town and received walk-in offers in Scandinavia. Companies across Europe have solicited Chinese investment. Bankers all over the world have touted lists of Western takeover candidates among China’s big firms. This year buyers based in China and Hong Kong have accounted for a tenth of global deals by value, including investments in oil and landmark takeovers in industry, such as Geely’s purchase of Volvo, a Swedish carmaker. A decade ago China urged its companies to expand under the slogan “go out”. Now it is really happening.
More deals are inevitable, given China’s rise. Control of the world’s stock of foreign direct investment (FDI), which includes takeovers and companies’ greenfield investments, tends to reflect a country’s economic muscle. Britain owned 45% of the world’s FDI in 1914; America’s share peaked at 50% in 1967. Today China, including Hong Kong and Macau, has a share of just 6% (see chart 1). Listed Chinese firms, which are largely state-controlled, are already some of the world’s biggest, and account for over a tenth of global stockmarket value. Most are still mainly domestic outfits.
China’s high savings will also spur deals. Companies often have surplus cash and banks surplus deposits. Today those savings are recycled into rich countries via sovereign-wealth funds and the central bank, which act as portfolio investors, buying mainly bonds. But China may and probably should diversify. That shift will be accelerated by China’s political aims: to acquire inputs, such as raw materials, labour and land; to build up technical and commercial expertise; and to gain access to foreign markets.
Public announcements of such deals are something of a charade. Wooden Chinese executives insist they are acting on purely commercial grounds. Western bosses hail a new era of co-operation. Yet these transactions are tricky partly because of cultural differences and partly because of the role of the Chinese state. There have been fiascos. In 2005 CNOOC, a Chinese oil firm, withdrew a bid for Unocal, a Californian producer, after American politicians kicked up a stink. In 2009 Rio Tinto, an Anglo-Australian mining firm, withdrew from a deal to sell a series of minority stakes to Chinalco, a Chinese metals firm. Rio’s shareholders opposed the sale but many reckon that the Australian government did, too.
The Economist has interviewed, anonymously, executives past and present at 11 Western companies that have been bought by or have sold stakes to Chinese firms, or have been in negotiations to do so. Ten of the deals discussed were worth more than $1 billion. What these people say provides an insight into both China’s capacity to expand its companies abroad and the opaque workings of its state-backed firms. The impression they give is a mixture of awe at China’s ambition and technical skill and a far more qualified assessment of Chinese companies’ ability to run international businesses.
The meat of the negotiation often has two parts: marathon sessions at an investment bank’s offices, often in London, and visits by target firms’ executives to mainland China or Hong Kong. There they may be expected to make epic PowerPoint presentations to giant audiences, and to attend banquets and intimate discussions, often in hotels owned by the bidder.
Most visitors are impressed by Chinese firms’ technical nous. Both sides try to make friends: “Emotion and trust matter,” says a Briton, because authority within Chinese firms is opaque and arbitrary. Chinese negotiators often use booze to break down barriers—and to try to get the upper hand. This is a well-known tactic, says a European of hazy days he spent in a hotel dealing with the fine print. “They would bring in people to try to get you drunk…At one point I was sure they’d brought in a lady from the switchboard.”
Most targets of Chinese takeovers need an interpreter. It pays to be wary. The head of a mining firm grew fond of his, but jokes, “She was clearly an internal spy.” Most executives say they trusted their hosts. But not all. A European says, “They knew everything about me,” and adds, “I had 52 hits from China on my home computer.” Another boss negotiating a controversial natural-resources deal found the atmosphere sinister. “You had to take your battery out of your mobile phone. You were told the rooms were bugged.”
Chinese companies’ power structure is a bit of a mystery to outsiders, even the handful of Westerners on the boards of big state-backed companies. A popular theory is that they are controlled by a parallel hierarchy of Communist Party officials. The most senior party man in a firm, the general secretary, is not necessarily the most senior executive. Although one Western executive says this distinction was evident (“There were party people and people who did stuff”), most are just overwhelmed by the volume of bodies. One arrived, alone, in London to be faced with 30-40 people from the Chinese side. “I was shocked,” he laughs. Meetings in China can be attended by vast audiences, with people coming in and out continually. A core of people ask good questions, but even they, many visitors say, seem to lack the authority, or desire, to make decisions.
The opacity of power is also reflected by the role of the titular heads of Chinese firms. One boss found his counterpart to be an autocrat, surrounded by minions: “You feel the deference towards this guy. There are no interjections when he speaks.” Yet most visitors to China talk of charming figureheads, for example at Sinopec: “There are two chairs in the middle where you and he sit…You say prepared remarks into the microphone and then everybody claps…Girls serve tea…The big chief doesn’t negotiate. He just blesses the deal.” Another executive says the head of Huawei, a telecoms-equipment firm, was “a great gentleman” who “relied on his lieutenants for information”. A natural-resources boss says the head of Minmetals, a big Chinese mining firm, was just there “to keep protocol”.
Who, then, calls the shots? A lieutenant who has lived outside China may lead the talks with the target’s top brass. Chinalco, says a Westerner, has used the same 40-something bilingual hotshot on several deals: he was “very, very good”. But with one exception, those interviewed thought the state was in ultimate control. “You can feel it,” says one. “In China you’re dealing with the government,” says another. “In India you’re dealing with companies.”
However, the state is far from being a predictable monolith. Often, more than one Chinese firm has sniffed out the same target. They compete for the Western firm’s affections and “preferred bidder” status with officials back home. The process can be chaotic. A chairman says he negotiated for months with a Chinese mining firm, including site visits by hundreds of their staff, only to see the deal collapse because it lacked political consent.
Likewise, China’s government-controlled banks, which have been expanding abroad (see chart 2), are often described as indiscriminate financiers of China’s overseas conquests. Yet the same chairman recalls going to Cuba to meet a senior official of China Development Bank (whose father had, apparently, been an acquaintance of Fidel Castro’s) and receiving a clear signal that a deal was in doubt. Another executive says a deal with ZTE, a maker of telecoms equipment, that included state-bank financing struggled to win official approval. ZTE’s bosses, he says, held little sway with the central government.
Once a preferred bidder has been picked, however, there can be a flood of cheap cash. Someone involved in the Rio deal recalls meeting a bank in China and being staggered by their indiscipline. “They said, ‘How much do you want: $10 billion, $20 billion?’ It was unbelievable.” The preferred firm’s negotiators often have some latitude to alter the terms of a deal, but refer big decisions to Beijing. During the auction of a Western oil company, a Chinese state-controlled energy firm “went back to the ministerial level to raise its bid”, says an executive of the target.
At key moments, though, this apparently fiddly hierarchy can be decisive. One oil executive ran an auction of a firm that ended with an Indian and a Chinese bidder (both were state-controlled). The Indians had “no concept of materiality”, he says, and were mired in nit-picking. In the final stages they returned the draft contract riddled with amendments. The Chinese firm returned it clean, and won.
Although to set up a foreign bid a Chinese firm has to jump through lots of hoops, once it has done so it enjoys formidable advantages. It has access to cheap finance. It can ignore its share price, since its majority shareholder, the government, is onside. Politicians may also work to smooth the waters. PetroKazakhstan, a Canadian firm with assets in Central Asia, was coveted by a Russian company. Its takeover by CNPC of China was eased by a state visit by the president, Hu Jintao, to Astana, the Kazakh capital.
China’s state-backed system also has disadvantages. One is that foreign governments are becoming increasingly wary of Chinese takeovers. These include those of Canada and Australia, previously two of the most open markets for corporate control in the world. Another is more subtle: that the style of decision-making can lead Chinese companies to overpay and to struggle to integrate their purchases.
Some executives felt that their Chinese suitors had bargained astutely. Someone who has sold four mining firms says the Chinese compared well with Western buyers. Others are less complimentary. To get to the point of executing a takeover, a Chinese company must build up a huge head of steam. Some say they struggle to rein in their investment bankers. “They lost control of the situation,” says a European chief executive. In future, “I hope for their sake that they do a better job at negotiating.”
Chinese firms also risk political fallout if they fail. Their sense of mission makes them “transparent”, says one European executive of his experience selling a firm. “They cannot take the chance to lose the deal.” Another European boss says his Chinese suitor struggled to deal with Western stockmarkets. Their disclosure rules mean slip-ups are made public, and disparate institutional investors are unpredictable. As a result Chinese buyers prefer targets with a single big shareholder who can negotiate bilaterally. However, buying such firms can be costly because they command a scarcity premium.
The price China pays is often dismissed as inconsequential: what are a few billion in the grand scheme of things? But even for rich countries, systematically overpaying for foreign assets is a bad idea. After a binge in the late 1980s and early 1990s, Japanese firms retrenched.
Integrating an acquisition is just as important as price. Once the deal is done—a text message from China confirming a higher offer is not unknown—there may be a signing ceremony in the target firm’s country and then a banquet in China, attended by central bankers and government ministers. More grog is compulsory. “You will leave the dinner completely drunk,” says a survivor. The bought firm’s bosses may be asked to linger in well-paid but largely symbolic roles.
Those interviewees who experienced Chinese firms’ integration efforts mostly reckon they began well. “They had done their homework,” says one. Their approach was “very clever” at first, recalls another. The buyer’s message that it would keep all staff “was extremely simple and well received”, he says. Usually the acquired company keeps some autonomy, with its own legal status and name. Only one executive, at a North American firm, felt this initial group hug was insincere: the Chinese took over “the day I walked out of the building…Critical positions were replaced instantly.” An ex-colleague disagrees, saying the Chinese just took firm control.
Over time, though, business plans change. Natural-resources firms can become captive suppliers to China, rather than selling on the open market. An executive of a Latin American mining company recalls a blazing row between the two groups of geologists which was resolved when the Westerners realised their new objective was to maximise production, not profits. In the longer term the DNA of Chinese corporations—a sense of mission, consensus, deference and opacity—can cause difficulties. These can be compounded by a dearth of English-speaking managers familiar with working outside China. An architect of a failed deal says, “There would have been some great opportunities—and some really big problems.”
The former boss of a European firm now owned by a Chinese giant says he liked his new colleagues but adds that the lack of open discussion caused friction. “Nobody contests what their immediate superior says. Never, never, never…The decisions are taken somewhere else.” The firm’s engineers became “frustrated” as plans were sent to China and amended. It is difficult for Chinese firms to run foreign ones, he says: “It is a very stratified society.” Another veteran of the same firm jokes about the “Beijing effect” and says that “having sold a business to them and worked for them for a year I don’t really have a clue how they work.” He adds: “Virtually all of the senior management have left and at the next level down people are looking [for new jobs].”
This isn’t true of all deals, but nor is it unique. The former boss of another European acquisition says of the integration plan: “On paper it looked quite good but it failed totally.” Decisions took months for “even the simplest things”. He says that “almost all the key people left” and adds that “there is no company left” at the headquarters, just a shell.
Does any of this matter? After all, Western takeovers can be brutal, too, and a buyer is by and large entitled to do as it pleases. Several mining and oil bosses also argue that a healthy process is at work, in which China buys firms and the capital and skilled people thus released are recycled into new start-up companies. Yet from Chinese firms’ perspective an inability to retain staff is a problem. Technical and local expertise accounts for much of a company’s value. And as China moves beyond digging stuff out of the ground—at which it is fairly adept—to more complex consumer industries, let alone creative ones, better management will be essential. In this, companies from other emerging markets, such as India and Brazil, have the advantage of private-sector credentials and more cosmopolitan cultures. The most durable multinational firms, such as Nestlé or Unilever, often transcend nationality.
A pessimistic view is that China will have to find other ways of “going out”. It could make passive equity investments through China Investment Corporation, a sovereign-wealth fund. Executives from two firms attest that its representatives take a back seat at board meetings. Joint ventures are another option. The boss of an oil firm with a Chinese partner says that “its motivation is not to take control” and that the relationship is harmonious.
Alternatively, Chinese companies could grow without buying. Until the wave of cross-border deals in the 1980s most firms went global by building operations from the ground up. Chinese firms are becoming good at this. One of them, COSCO, has a concession to run part of Greece’s biggest port. Chinese construction firms have won contracts across Africa and eastern Europe. Huawei has developed without making large acquisitions.
For all that, it is hard to believe that China’s companies and politicians want to operate with one arm tied behind their backs. And although many of the country’s big firms may never resemble Western ones, with diffuse private shareholders and independence from the state, they may have to edge more towards this template in order to succeed at large cross-border deals. In a speech this month a senior Chinese official emphasised the role abroad of China’s “private” firms, which typically have less overt state direction. To address other countries’ concerns about political control, China may also have to loosen its hold on its giant state-owned companies and ensure that their power structure is more transparent.
Most of the executives interviewed by The Economist also felt that the next generation of Chinese executives, in their 30s and 40s today, with more international education and experience, would prove far more effective than the present cohort of chiefs. Over the past two decades the old guard has taken a rusting industrial base and from it made gleaming corporate giants. Yet if those firms are to achieve their full potential abroad their creators may have to relax their grip.
13 November 2010
G-20 refuses to back US push on yuan
SEOUL: Leaders of 20 major economies on Friday refused to endorse a US push to get China to let its currency rise, keeping alive a dispute that has raised the specter of a global trade war.
At the end of their two-day summit, the leaders of the Group of 20 rich and developing economies — including President Barack Obama and China's Hu Jintao — issued a watered-down statement that only said they agreed to refrain from ``competitive devaluation'' of currencies.
Such a statement is of little consequence since countries usually only devalue their currencies in extreme situations like a severe financial crisis.
The real dispute is over Washington's allegations that Beijing resorts to ``competitive undervaluation'' — artificially keeping its currency, the yuan, weak to gain a trade advantage. But the US position itself has been undermined by its own recent policy of printing money to boost a sluggish economy, which is weakening the dollar.
The joint statement avoided the words ``competitive undervaluation,'' which was a reference to China's currency policy that had been inserted into a draft of the statement by officials during pre-summit negotiations.
The dispute over whether China and the United States are manipulating their currencies is threatening to resurrect destructive protectionist policies like those that worsened the Great Depression in the 1930s.
The biggest fear is that trade barriers will send the global economy back into recession. A law the United States passed in 1930 that raised tariffs on imports is widely thought to have deepened the Great Depression by stifling trade.
The G-20 leaders pledged to move toward more market-determined exchange rate systems and enhance exchange rate flexibility. Although directed against China, the statement leaves significant room for interpretation since the language is vague and does not impose any timeframe for enforcing a market-determined exchange rate.
The US says a higher-valued yuan would make Chinese exports costlier abroad and make US imports cheaper for the Chinese to buy. It would shrink the US trade deficit with China, which is on track this year to match its 2008 record of $268 billion, and encourage Chinese companies to sell more to their own consumers rather than rely so much on the US and others to buy low-priced Chinese goods.
Other countries are irate over the Federal Reserve's plans to pump $600 billion into the sluggish American economy. They see that move as a reckless and selfish scheme to flood markets with dollars, driving down the value of the US currency and giving American exporters an advantage.
Some critics warn that US interest rates kept too low for too long could inflate new bubbles in the prices of commodities, stocks and other assets. Developing countries like Thailand and Indonesia fear that falling yields on US government bonds will send money flooding their way in search of higher returns. Such emerging markets could be left vulnerable to a crash if investors later decide to pull out and move their money elsewhere.
Friday's statement is unlikely to immediately resolve the most vexing problem facing the G-20 members: how to fix a global economy that's long been nourished by huge US trade deficits with China, Germany and Japan.
Exports to the United States powered those countries' economies for years. But they've also produced enormous trade gaps for the US because Americans consume far more in foreign goods and services than they sell abroad.
10 November 2010
Why is America so rich?
From The Economist
ECONOMIC gloom and doom aside, America remains the world's richest large country. It's generally estimated to have a per capita GDP level around $45,000, while the richest European nations manage only a $40,000 or so per capita GDP (setting aside low population, oil-rich states like Norway). Wealth underlies America's sense of itself as a special country, and it's also cited as evidence that America is better than other economies on a range of variables, from economic freedom to optimism to business savvy to work ethic.
But why exactly is America so rich? Karl Smith ventures an explanation:
I am going to go pretty conventional on this one and say a combination of three big factors
- The Common Law
- Massive Immigration
- The Great Scientific Exodus during WWII
You’ll notice that four of the top five countries in the Human Development Index have the Common Law and the top, Norway, is a awash in oil. Without the petro-kronors they probably wouldn’t be so hot.
You’ll also notice that 3 of the top 4, again with Norway the odd man out, are immigrant nations. The founder effect here should be clear.
The bonus from the great exodus is definitely waning. Most of our hey-day German and Jewish scientists are dying off, but its still given us a boost that lingers to this day. There is no fundamental reason why the US should be the center of the scientific world but for a time it was the only place in the world safe for many scientists.
It's a difficult question to tackle because there's so very much to it. America jumped to a huge productivity lead early last century by developing a resource- and capital-intense, high-throughput style of manufacturing producing mass market goods. The fractious, class-riven European continent struggled to copy this technology, and while adoption of these methods eventually led to a period of rapid catch-up growth, the process of catch-up was never quite completed. And so that's one gap to explore.
There's also the question of what exactly one is comparing. What if we take similar European and American metropolitan areas and adjust for human capital and hours worked? On that basis, the difference between America and northern Europe looks relatively small. One might then focus on the ways in which America's more integrated domestic market leads to a lower level of within-continent inequality, even though national inequality levels in Europe compare favourably with America's.
The size of the market may be more important than we imagine. As Mr Smith notes, four of the top five HDI countries share the Common Law. They also speak English. In a world in which national and cultural barriers still bite, America's wealth could be chalked up to the fact that it's a uniquely large and uniform nation. Common rules, culture, language, and so on facilitate high levels of trade and mobility. National and cultural barriers within Europe, by contrast, work to limit the extent to which the economic potential of the continent can be reached.
Mr Smith also gets at something important in discussing immigration and talent. The economic geography of the world is lumpy, and talent likes to clump together into centres of innovation. Through fortune and foresight, America managed to develop world-leading centres of talent in places like Silicon Valley, Boston, and New York. Relatively open immigration rules and the promise of a safe harbour for war refugees, including persecuted Jews, helped build these knowledge centres. When one combines that innovative capacity with a system that makes it relatively easy to develop ideas and relatively lucrative to exploit them economically, the potential is there for rapid and sustained growth.
America does seem to be special in important ways, but it's not always clear what those ways are. A liberal economic order and geographically mobile population are important, but so is the level of education, the promise of social mobility, and the openness of America's borders. It's worth keeping all of that in mind as the country's leaders think about the ways economic policy should change in the wake of the Great Recession.